Showing posts with label "book review". Show all posts
Showing posts with label "book review". Show all posts

Friday, July 23, 2010

Bobos in Paradise

By Stephen Malpezzi, Professor and Lorin & Marjorie Tiefenthaler Distinguished Chair of Real Estate

Whatever your politics, discerning readers of the op-ed columns recognize center-right columnist David Brooks as one of the very best at his craft. Trained as a journalist but knowledgeable about a range of social sciences, his book Bobos in Paradise gave a popular introduction to “bourgeois bohemians,” a word Brooks coined to describe the nineties version of earlier “yuppies:” upper-class, educated, and ready to spend, but on goods (argues Brooks) like granite countertops or high-end electronics that are positioned as functional, rather than something expensive but frivolous from the Neiman-Marcus Christmas catalog. (Colleague David Shulman recommended the book to me, and it makes my Reading for Life list.)

Brooks has written two recent columns that speak to me as we prepare for the year’s classes and an influx of students. The first column appeared in The New York Times on July 9th (“The Medium Is the Medium”). In it, Brooks nods to the many benefits of the Internet, email and the rise of social media, but he also makes a pitch for the importance of old-fashioned books. Readers of my introduction to Reading for Life will know this is a position I’ve staked out as well. Research by Jacob Vigdor and Helen Ladd, cited by Brooks, is the most comprehensive study I’ve ever seen on the impact of personal computers on student achievement. This study, “Scaling the Digital Divide: Home Computer Technology and Student Achievement,” is still in working paper form but is destined to become a classic (I’ll address it more fully in a future entry). The take-away for the moment is this: simply providing your child a PC and an Internet connection is no guarantee that they’ll excel in school; in fact it may bring their performance down. Books, on the other hand, rule.

The other recent Brooks column that speaks to our educational mission is the July 13th “An Economy of Grinds.” Brooks describes “princes” as business people, often those at the top, who have great social skills, including an ability to integrate and “tell a story” about a situation. “Grinds,” on the other hand, are driven loners, often almost anti-social, ready to take a contrarian view. Both can be arrogant, but the grinds, while not always obvious about it, are often really arrogant. Citigroup’s Charles Prince (he’s even got the name!), “as long as the music’s playing, you’ve got to get up and dance,” versus Michael Barry, one of the first to get the MBS market right, rarely left his office and took poor investor relations to a new level.

But really, Brooks is not completely fair to either grinds or princes. The best business leaders combine both. Think Jack Welch, not Alec Baldwin’s Jack Donaghy on 30 Rock. Or think of our own James Graaskamp’s oft-quoted statement that a UW grad should be a combination of da Vinci, Muir and Rouse.

At Wisconsin, our goal should be to turn out grinds who can tell a story, princes who aren’t in thrall to the latest investment fad. Our students and alums need to think independently but be able to communicate—both up and down the food chain!—inspire and persuade. In future posts, we’ll talk about some of the hard and soft skills we all need to master throughout a lifetime of learning.


“The result [of an academic program] should be a real estate entrepreneur with the creativity of Leonardo da Vinci, the sensitivity for the natural world of John Muir and the political humanity with cash management for profit of James Rouse.”
James A. Graaskamp (1933-1988), professor and chair of the UW-Madison Department of Real Estate and Urban Land Economics

Tuesday, June 22, 2010

Reading for Life: Nature's Metropolis

Book recommendation from Professor Stephen Malpezzi's Reading for Life list:

Cronon, William. Nature's Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West. W.W. Norton, 1991.

Bill Cronon is the Frederick Jackson Turner and Vilas Research Professor of History, Geography, and Environmental Studies at UW–Madison. He is a leading historian on environmental issues as well as the development of Chicago.

In his book, he explains how Chicago rose from a small Midwestern town of just a few thousand people to one of the big U.S. cities in only a few decades. The city's position as a focal point for the meatpacking and farming industries blossomed as a result of the railway connecting it with the East Coast and the invention of the refrigerated rail car.

Even though the book is principally about Chicago, much is written about the surrounding area of Illinois and southern Wisconsin. Madison's particular contribution was ice. Lakes Mendota and Monona supplied ice that cooled those refrigerated boxcars.

Just the thing on a hot summer day! Read more about Professor Malpezzi's Reading for Life list here and catch up on previous posts in the series here.

Tuesday, January 5, 2010

Reading for life

Stephen Malpezzi shares one of the titles on his "Reading for Life" book list.

At Wisconsin, we’re big on the idea of “lifetime learning.” The few years you spend in Madison in Bucky’s warm embrace are only the beginning of your real estate education. We want to partner with your education over the following 50 years, too. And, consistent with the Wisconsin Idea that the university has no boundaries, we want to be a part of your education even if you’ve never been lucky enough to set foot in Mad City.

In my urban economics courses, I try to find time to point out books and articles outside that course’s curriculum that fit that lifetime learning model. In that spirit, from time to time I’ll use this blog for short book reviews.

Let’s start with one of my recent favorites, In Fed We Trust: Ben Bernanke’s War on the Great Panic; How the Federal Reserve became the Fourth Branch of Government. If the full title is a little long, the double subtitles do give a fair view of the contents. The book was written by David Wessel, the Wall Street Journal's economics editor, and frequent contributor to National Public Radio. He is a very interesting and generally reliable voice on economic matters.

In Fed We Trust tells the story of the fall 2008 economic crisis, through the perspective of the actions of Fed Chairman Bernanke and a small group of policymakers, including Henry Paulson at Treasury, Timothy Geithner (then at the New York Fed), Kevin Warsh at the Fed, and others like FDIC’s Sheila Bair and the SEC’s Christopher Cox.

We're still in the middle of the economic crisis, and academics will argue over the causes and the policy responses for decades. Nevertheless, this book is a terrific first look. It's a clear and readable narrative focusing on a particularly critical time. Other books and articles dig deeper into the root causes, and present more data and analytics – see, for example, Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair a Failed System, edited by Viral Acharya and Matthew Richardson; or Jim Barth’s Rise and Fall of the U.S. Mortgage and Credit Markets.

The broad outlines of the crisis are familiar. Over the long run, house prices in the U.S. rise slightly more than inflation, on average (see: Malpezzi and Maclennan, The Price Elasticity of Supply of New Housing in the U.S. and the United Kingdom, Journal of Housing Economics, 2001). But as my colleague Morris Davis and I show in this chart, starting around 1996, U.S. house prices began a decade-long run-up, increasing an inflation-adjusted average of 7 percent per year, clearly an unsustainable situation. Nevertheless, many borrowers, lenders, investors, and some analysts and policymakers appeared to believe large real house prices could be sustained indefinitely, in defiance of history and logic. After the 2007 turn in housing markets, and the subsequent collapse of mortgage backed security and other markets, by September 2008, U.S. financial markets and indeed the entire economy stared into an abyss. This book is the story of the small group of key officials whose responses to that crisis plausibly they kept us from falling into the abyss.

We all know that will never know the true counterfactual – exactly what would've happened to the economy really if the actions described in this book had not been undertaken. Based on the available data and reportage, my personal view is that it would have been extremely dire indeed. A complete freeze up of the global financial system could have led to a much larger contraction in real economic activity and does walk taken us down a path of deflation and extreme unemployment from which recovery would take years – see Japan’s experience. During this period Bernanke et al. dealt with massive failures at Bear Stearns, Lehman Brothers, AIG, IndyMac, Fannie and Freddie, and others.

It's interesting to contrast Bernanke with his predecessor Alan Greenspan. As an economist, by all accounts Greenspan is an excellent clarinet player. As a fellow data freak, I have to admit to a certain admiration for Greenspan's eclectic data-diving. But even data freaks need a good conceptual framework, and an ability to do serious empirics that make sense of the data; or at least we have to understand the frameworks and empirics of others. A good economist also needs to know when to step back and give up on a particular view. Keynes’ famous statement, “When I find I’m mistaken, I change my mind. What do you do?" comes to mind. Bernanke went into the crisis with many of the same prior beliefs as Greenspan, more or less. But it’s impossible to overestimate the importance of this difference between the two men: when events showed their prior beliefs about the economy’s workings, and the Fed’s appropriate policies, were mistaken, Greenspan was left only with an ideology, and his deep yet by then irrelevant knowledge of the more obscure economic statistics. Bernanke had the flexibility to adjust his conceptual framework, and move into a mode that was demanded by events. Nor did his flexibility devolve into a paralyzing uncertainty about the actions to be taken, once he believed he understood the situation.

Especially at this early stage it’s important not to turn hagiographic and believe Bernanke, or his policies, are better than they were. Nevertheless, from everything we know at this writing, we can be thankful we had Bernanke at the helm of the Fed in 2008. Henry Paulson by contrast comes across the way he did to many of us watching C-SPAN and reading the newspapers at the time: someone who was surprisingly ineffective at communicating just what they were doing or why. Last year more than once I found myself yelling at the television set as Paulson would again fail to articulate a focused diagnosis of the crisis or a clear rationale for their actions. Nevertheless, I have sympathy for Paulson’s position, too. As Treasury vacillated between a planned reverse auction to set prices for dodgy assets and flooding the market with liquidity, I did and still find it hard to be certain from Madison how much of the financial institutions’ problems were liquidity and how much was insolvency. Knowing the difference is the key, and it’s hard: I’m reminded of what I sometimes tell our students: “If you’re not confused, you’re simply not yet thinking clearly.” This book won’t sort out everything we need to know about the crisis and its aftermath; that book hasn’t been written, and I’m not sure it ever will. But In Fed We Trust is a great, readable start.

For a focus on liquidity as the prime issue, see work by John Cochrane.

One of the economists consistently emphasizing the role of insolvency has been Nouriel Roubini.

For more general discussion see Wisconsin Real Estate's insights on the crisis.